Advanced Oregon Water Law Seminar

Tough times dictate that we cut our discretionary spending.  Property owners may defer some maintenance and other due diligence.  But spending money on education and protecting your property interests must be considered a continued important investment that is not discretionary.

Hunkering down and waiting for it to pass us by will not work.  Business as usual will not work because the usual isn’t any more.  Everything has changed. It is unlikely that what we once thought “normal” will ever be again.

For only $75, you will be both educated and entertained at a full day advanced water rights educational seminar.  Register at www.water-law.com.  If you missed our bootcamp, no matter:  We will answer any questions you bring to the advanced seminar to raise you to the advanced level!

Another opportunity for only $375 is to have us make a specific public records request and pull all your water rights files to provide you with a full electronic copy. Likely you keep your deed to the property is a safe place, your water right files should have equal status.  Many property owners have more value in their water rights than the dirt and don’t even know it.  At minimum, we recommend obtaining your water rights files.  Email Ms. Daryl Cole:  d.cole@water-law.com to obtain a water rights authorization form to make this due diligence investment.




Limiting the Domestic Well Exemption

Most Western states allow an exemption from water right permitting for domestic wells.  In New Mexico this exemption was recently challenged as being inconsistent with the prior appropriation doctrine.  Other western states seek to legislatively limit the scope of such exemptions.

Oregon which has perhaps the broadest statutory groundwater exemption is seeking in this legislative session to reduce the allowable group domestic exemption.  Given the pressure to establish critical and limited groundwater areas in Oregon, such a reduction should be given some environmental and practical consideration.

Interestingly, the opponents to the reduction come from the agricultural sector, those who are most affected by group domestic withdrawals which impact aquifer recharge and thus critical and limited groundwater area water rights.  One must presume that the natural law rights to domestic water weigh heavier in the minds of the opponents than the allocation issue.




Oregon Water Coalition Friend of Farmer Award

The Oregon Water Coalition has asked Laura  Schroeder to present Chet Prior with its annual “Friend of Farmer” award on January 27, 2009, in Hermiston, Oregon.

The Oregon Water Coalition actively supports water development projects including the recently funded research to develop aquifer recharge and aquifer storage in the critical ground water areas located in Morrow and Umatilla Counties.

Attorneys Cortney Duke and Therese Ure presented a half day seminar at the January 27 Hermiston meeting on “hot topics” in water law including: exempt well use, sharing and stacking groundwater exemptions;  critical groundwater regulation and compliance; forfeiture of water rights in critical groundwater areas; reclamation contracts and jurisdiction; Overlap of Division 33/Peak Flows, Division 9 and Scenic waterways; and Oregon water courts.  Many of these topics may be considered in the 2009 session of the Oregon Legislature and in the Oregon administrative rule making process.




Reno Center of Northern Nevada Water Issues

Accepting associations and referrals in Oregon, Washington, Idaho and Nevada, Schroeder Law Offices recently opened its new office in Reno, Nevada.  With a population of 250,000, Reno is at the center of water controversies on the Truckee, Carson, and Walker rivers.

Each of these desert rivers interestingly terminate at a lake with an associated Indian reservations adding to the possible legal issues.  Municipal and agricultural interests use and divert waters from these rivers adding to the on-going controversies over high valued water.  With the official opening of its staffed office in October, Schroeder Law Offices plans to expand its Nevada natural resources clientele.




Last 2008 Bootcamp

Colm Moore and Laura Schroeder will present a 4-hour seminar on Nevada water rights in Winnemucca on December 9 and in Elko on December 10. For more information click here.




Payette National Forest Draft EIS Released

PAYETTE NATIONAL FOREST RELEASES A DRAFT EIS AS RELATED TO BIGHORN SHEEP AND DOMESTIC SHEEP THAT OMITS COMMITMENTS MADE IN 1997 AND THAT OMITS ANALYSIS OF MANY CRITICAL ELEMENTS

By Alan Schroeder

To view the full text of this press release please click here.

Weiser, Idaho. October 7, 2008. Is removing domestic sheep from the Payette National Forest (PNF) the answer to protecting bighorn sheep? The Forest Service says yes, but Ron Shirts of Shirts Brothers Sheep and Frank Shirts, Jr. — who are third generation domestic sheep operators that are permitted to graze on several domestic sheep allotments in the Payette National Forest — disagree.

The Forest Service released a Draft Supplemental Environmental Impact Statement (DEIS) on September 18, 2008. The Forest Service proposes in its DEIS to eliminate domestic sheep grazing on all but 4 domestic sheep allotments within the PNF in an effort to protect the bighorns due to a claimed disease transmission problem between the bighorns and the domestic sheep.

The Forest Service’s proposal ignores the fact that the bighorns in Hells Canyon in Idaho were reintroduced only through a commitment that the domestic sheep operators would be held harmless from any disease transmission problem associated with the bighorn reintroduction.

Beyond the 1997 commitment, the Forest Service’s proposal is based upon a premise that certain pathogens (bugs) exist which bighorns and domestic sheep can share, and that if these bugs are transmitted between the two animals, the bugs may cause the death of the bighorns. However, there are several elements that are necessary to confirm this premise, including, but not limited to, the following: (1) The scientific research needs to document that disease transmission occurs between bighorns and domestic sheep; (2) he facts need to disclose that the bighorns themselves are free of the offending bugs; (3) The facts need to disclose that the domestic sheep upon the allotments are carriers of the offending bugs. The Forest Service ignores any discussion in its DEIS of these elements in an apparent effort to advocate for the objective to separate the bighorns and domestic sheep and to eliminate domestic sheep allotments on the PNF.

Comments should be submitted before January 2, 2009, asking the Forest Service to redo its DEIS and to maintain the existing domestic sheep allotments on the PNF. In so asking, you will not be advocating for or against bighorns or for or against domestic sheep. Instead, you will be advocating for an objective analysis of bighorn and domestic sheep interaction and for ratification of the commitments made in 1997.




Time to Create Water Management Plans

With food prices at all time highs, agricultural market prices rising, and water rights at a premium, now is the time to plan for the future.  We suggest that water users create and update water management plans with an eye to water rights security, stability, and development.  A water management plan will analyze the current state of the water rights designated and appurtenant to property or other boundary and will provide a tool to consider options for their use, development or marketing.  One can begin this work by emailing Kelley Wesson for a water rights authorization packet.




Remebering John Keyes

Retired Reclamation Commissioner John Keyes passing is sad news. I first “engaged” Reclamation with John at the helm in the Boise Regional office in 1992 when working for the Teel Irrigation District. We were dealing with issues surrounding “water spreading” then making headlines in the Umatilla Project by Water Watch of Oregon. Over the years, we kept in close touch on various Reclamation issues. Most recently, John assisted me in obtaining a position with the USAID working in Armenia. He was a southern gentleman in the best way. Kind and considerate always interested in a balance between what was best for the individual as well as the public. He told me that retirement to him meant a chance to spend more time flying.




Northern Idaho Adjudication

Focusing on the soon to be launched adjudication in north Idaho, water and real estate lawyers gathered in Coeur d”Alene, Idaho May 15 and 16, 2008.

As in other McCarran adjudications in which we are involved, issues expected to be included will be federal including Indian, Forest Service and Reclamation issues; instream including hydro, water quality, and endangered species issues; and state issues including municipal, water district, and individual claims. It is likely that in all adjudications, the best water attorneys will be picked up early and conflicted out quickly. Speaker Steven C. Moore, a staff attorney for the Native American Rights Fund out of Boulder, Colorado, quoted Professor Drew Kershen at the University of Oklahoma College of Law stating “A good water rights case can be willed to your kids.”

We suggest that our clients and potential clients contact us early to prepare and review potential claims BEFORE the claim is filed.




Rio Grande Project Agreement Reached

An historic agreement has been reached in a dispute over water in the Rio Grande Project. It has taken 29 years in a process stagnated by several lawsuits to prepare an operating agreement negotiated between the Bureau of Reclamation, Elephant Butte Irrigation District (EBID), and the El Paso County Water Improvement District No. 1. No previous operating agreement has been signed by either of these districts. Rather, they have been complying with the Bureau’s requests and procedures on a yearly basis. In working to negotiate the new operating agreement, EBID used the “Managing for Excellence” report prepared by the Bureau of Reclamation to guide settlement discussions.

The Managing for Excellence Plan was created in response to a comprehensive report regarding the Bureau’s construction and infrastructure, prepared by the National Research Council and the National Academy of Sciences. Ultimately, the principles outlined in the Managing for Excellence report helped to develop an agreement which aims to increase transparency, cost effectiveness, and efficiency while allowing irrigation districts some independence in their operation. The agreement will also allow regional issues to be addressed and will allow for carryover of conserved water to be stored in project reservoirs on a yearly basis, promoting recreation and allowing upstream storage of water. The agreement is notable not only for resolving this long standing dispute, but also for establishing an interstate agreement between New Mexico and Texas, which could be used as a model for other states.

To read the full operating agreement visit http://ebid-nm.org/static/pdf/opag/opag.pdf.
To learn more about other water issues like this visit the Family Farm Alliance at http://www.familyfarmalliance.org/ and click on the Water Review Link.




Auditing Management Contracts

Armenia’s Public Services Regulatory Commission (PSRC) has suggested that new operator contracts with Yerevan Water require provisions requiring audit controls. Given some commentator’s thoughts on the management failures of the present agreements this request is not surprising.

Providing contract requirements for audits is not uncommon. However, determining what audit level is appropriate for a domestic water utility management contract is not easy. Regardless, it is a necessity. Comprehensive management audits can cost upwards of hundreds of thousands of dollars so selecting appropriate management criteria to limit output is critical to obtaining a true picture of management. As Armenia moves forward with new contracts between the Joint State-Controlled Stock Companies, it will be interesting to note, not if, but what auditing mechanisms will be selected.




Elections and Water Code Revisions

The government of Armenia is inaugurating a new president on Wednesday, April 9, at 2 in the afternoon. Large crowds are expected in the downtown area in connection with the official events, which will include a military procession through Freedom Square and evening festivities at Republic Square.

It is not expected that much dramatic change will occur in Armenia with the inauguration. However, the Presidential election process, has substantially delayed our efforts to complete the revisions to the water code and place it before the legislative assembly for adoption.

In addition to the process delay, the State Committee has “filibustered” revisions to the water code involving sections of the water code related to dam inspection and safety, the transfer of the water system use permit, and the authorities of the Public Services Regulatory Commission (PSRC) as to the issuance of the water system use permit (WSUP). The WSUP permit is issued in Armenia to those operators who hold management or lease contracts with the State Committee acting through a joint stock company for operations of the water system. In most cases, the joint stock ownership is 51% to the State Committee and 49% to the local government “owning” the water system facilities.

Thus, the State Committee does not want revisions to the Water Code that would make it “beholding” in the sense of WSUP requirements or conditions for system inspections, control of tariff setting (and therefore “income” to the Operator), or other regulatory controls necessary to protect the public that the PSRC would hold if the water code revisions were adopted. If the State Committee continues to “filibuster” these changes, a ministry level committee is in charge of resolving any remaining issues to the revisions. This committee is scheduled to meet April 18th.




Water Facilities Permitting in Armenia

Armenia’s current water code requires a water system use permit (WSUP) without exception for any system of facilities. The WSUP is issued by the Public Services Regulatory Commission (PSRC). It has been suggested municipalities and small community water associations that own and operate their own domestic water delivery system should be exempt from the requirement for a WSUP. The major reason for the exemption would be to prevent dual regulation, ie regulation by the locals and also by the state through the PSRC. In addition, where access to the local person operating the water system can be made by “visiting with the neighbor across the street”, consumer and often times operator are one and the same. In such circumstances over arching state regulation is not required.

Since the PSRC has not enforced the WSUP requirement against the locals, the need for changes in the present water code may be overlooked at present. The real reason in fact may be that very few local delivery schemes exist (except rurally). Armenia’s urban population receives water services by conveying their water facilities to the State in return for a 49% in a joint stock company controlled by the State which owns a 51% share. The stock company then contracts with a third party operator for water services.

These Company-Operator contracts are “issues of public importance.” As such, the Prime Minister of Armenia appoints a Commission to develop and approve these contracts. Since the Yerevan Jur contract is up for tender in October 2008, it is expected that a Commission will be appointed soon. This Commission may well set the stage for the four other water companies who exist in Armenia who will also need new tenders in the near future. This process of developing the new contract for Yerevan Jur may well set the stage to move further into water sector privatization or not.




Private Participation Contracts for Water Section

Development of public owner-private operator contracts in the water sector is largely a reflection of the extent of private sector participation. International literature on the subject generally describes the various forms of these Private Sector Participation Contracts (“PSP contracts”) as (1) Service contracts; (2) Management contracts; (3) Leasing contracts; (4) BOT type contracts; (5) Concessions; and (6) Divestiture under license (BOO) arrangements.

An article entitled: Guidelines for Performance-Based Contracts between Municipalities and Water Utilities in Eastern Europe, Caucasus and Central Asia (EECCA) provides a very good summary of these contracts. Excerpts from this article are provided below:

In a service contract the private contractor provides agreed services to the public authority under the public authority’s general control and supervision. Service contracts are a potentially beneficial form of PSP where there is strong political or community opposition to wider involvement of the private sector and if there is opposition to water tariff increases which are generally required for many of the other forms of PSP (e.g., lease contract).

A management contract is a more comprehensive form of service contract, under which the public authority appoints a private contractor to manage all or part of its operations. Under such contracts, the bulk of the commercial risk and all the capital and investment risks remain with the government. These contracts are useful if the core objective is to increase a utility’s technical efficiency for performance of specific tasks. If management contracts include clauses which link the contract payments to utility performance, they come closer to the lease and concession arrangements [footnote]. Like service contracts, management contracts can lead to improvements in service for those customers who are connected to the network but they provide little potential for improved access by those potential customers who are not connected to the network. Management contracts are a potentially beneficial form of PSP when there is strong political or public reluctance to water tariff rises or there is concern about handing over more control to the private sector. Management contracts may also be the preferred approach if potential private sector investors consider that the risks associated with a higher level of private involvement are currently too high. If this course is followed, the government can seek to address some of the risk factors over the duration of the contract. For example, the government may implement changes in tariff and regulatory structures to facilitate a greater preparedness for private sector risk taking in the future.

Under a lease contract, a water utility leases the full operation and maintenance of its facilities within an agreed geographic area to a private operator for a period of time, say, ten years. The contract grants the operator the right to invoice and collect charges from customers within that area. The public utility would own the assets and remain responsible for major extensions and upgrades. The operator would be consulted on all major works, especially when the continuity of service is involved, and may participate in tender evaluation or submit its own tender.

Under a best practice lease contract, the private operator would take the full commercial risk on all operations within its lease area, with its remuneration directly linked to the charges it collects from customers. From these charges, it would pay the public utility a rental fee intended to cover the public utility’s capital costs in extending or upgrading the facilities.

Under a lease contract, the operator is usually required to finance the renewal of plant and equipment. At the termination of the contract, the government would compensate the operator for the works it had financed that had not yet been fully amortized.

The management of such works (preparation, procurement, and supervision) would be the operator’s full responsibility. Best practice lease contracts have built-in incentives that encourage the private operators to:

  • Update customer files and implement efficient collection procedures to improve the collection ratio from customers (including government agencies);
  • Implement an aggressive commercial policy aimed at servicing more customers to increase the revenue base;
  • Reduce operating costs to maximize profits;
  • Carry out regular maintenance to increase the reliability of plant and equipment and postpone their renewal; and
  • Make decisions, not only on day-to-day management issues, but also on improvement of the facilities for which the operator is responsible.

Build-own-operate-transfer (BOOT, a.k.a. BOT or ROT) schemes are an adaptation of leasing contracts specifically designed for investments in water infrastructure which require extensive rehabilitation. Under these arrangements, the private sector typically designs, constructs and operates facilities, and provides services to municipal or government owned water utilities. Generally, any existing underlying assets are leased for a limited period, often 15 to 30 years. Contracts should be designed to allocate risks between the private operator and the public utility, preferably according to capacity to manage and minimize risk.

In contrast with lease contracts, BOT type contracts allocate much more of the commercial risk for specific projects to private parties rather than governments. They can also provide a relatively quick method for mobilizing project based non-recourse finance for new capital investment in developing countries, particularly where capital markets are poorly developed.

BOTs are generally production or bulk supply focused. Such bulk supply investments cannot deal with the major problems of high unaccounted-for-losses in water distribution systems. Nor do they allow private operators to seek out new customers and expand their operations where it is commercially viable. In general, BOTs are not likely to remedy a utility’s faulty (leaking) distribution system or its poor collection processes.

BOT schemes, because they do not involve management of distribution systems down to the household or business meter, are easier to implement than more comprehensive private sector models such as retail concessions, which require more extensive negotiation of contracts. In economies with poorly defined regulatory and legal structures and emerging capital markets, BOT schemes can be implemented relatively quickly and provide a building block for subsequent PSP in the rest of the distribution system.

Effective implementation of BOT/ROT type contracts requires careful attention to the design of tender documents and can involve a relatively lengthy bidding process. Experience with some BOTs shows that they have achieved some savings in capital construction costs and facilitated more rapid investment in infrastructure. However, they can also have a downside in that they can be an expensive way of substituting private debt for public debt, if there is an expensive take-or-pay contract for sale of bulk water to the retail utility.

Many BOTs have failed to deliver optimal outcomes for government or consumers. This is because the government’s agency responsible for negotiating allowed too much of the risk to remain with government – especially where (foreign exchange) guarantees on commercial risks are provided or where take or pay contracts are signed. On the other hand, private operators will not submit bids for BOTs if they feel that the government has attempted to transfer too much risk to the private sector.

Concession contracts combine elements of operation leases for existing assets and BOT contracts for major rehabilitation investments. Under concession contracts, a private operator is given a contractual right to use existing infrastructure assets to supply customers.
However, the concession contract also includes obligations to finance extensions and upgrades to the existing water supply. This tends to result in concession contracts being of longer duration than lease contracts to enable the operator to recover its capital and financing costs.

Management of all capital extensions and upgrades, as well as normal maintenance, is often entirely the responsibility of the operator. Procurement, in particular, could follow acceptable commercial practices that are often different from those required of public agencies.

In comparison to single project BOT type schemes, concessions leave greater flexibility in the hands of the operator in determining the nature and timing of the investments they make to achieve contractual supply obligations. Typically, under a concession agreement, the constructor and operators also are given
the right to supply retail services direct to customers.

For some water supply networks, for example those spanning an entire state or large city, it may also be possible to have a number of concessions operating at the one time. This would have the potential advantage of enabling government to compare the performance of concessionaires, to assess the price and quality of their services, and to evaluate the adequacy of investment programs for meeting community needs. There may also be potential to allow some level of competition between concessionaires, say, for large commercial customers using third party access arrangements.
The rights to provide services under concession arrangements can be awarded through a process of competitive tendering for the concession contract or through direct negotiation. An advantage of competitive bidding for concession contracts is that it limits the scope for monopoly pricing, and thereby avoids the requirement for heavy-handed industry regulation. However, there can be trade-offs when the competitive bidding process determines the successful tender with reference to the lowest supply price to consumers. This is because low prices are not always conducive to efficient demand management of the water resource. If the competitive bidding process involves a range of quantitative variables, such as reductions in unaccounted-for-water or increased use of meters, the selection process becomes more complicated as these qualitative variables are likely to differ between bids.

Thorough preparation and negotiation of scopes of works are required for all concessions to prevent experienced concessionaires extracting advantageous terms. Again, as in BOT contracts, care must be taken not to transfer too much risk to the private sector or they will not bid. In all cases, the regulatory framework for the concession will be important in determining its success.

PSP in infrastructure can also be achieved through the direct sale of infrastructure assets to the private sector. Private ownership of assets may be achieved through either 100 percent private ownership or JVs with public sector corporations. In either case, government retains the regulatory role.

Divestiture can be by way of sale of assets, sale of shares or management buy-out. Like divestiture, BOO contracts require removal of constraints to private sector entry in the water sector and the introduction of
competitive market structures or regulation by government.

In a full divestiture or BOO arrangement, the private sector has full responsibility for operations, maintenance, and investment in a utility. In contrast to a concession, these arrangements transfer assets to the private sector. In a concession, the government continues to own the utility’s assets and is therefore responsible for ensuring that the assets are used efficiently and, in particular, returned to the government in the appropriate condition at the end of the
concession period. Furthermore, the government needs to ensure customers are protected from poor service and monopolistic pricing.

Under divestiture or BOO, it should be the private company’s concern to operate, design and maintain the asset base. The government, on the other hand, would concern itself with the regulation of the water utility, which commonly involves a license to operate a water supply system.

Although the private company has ownership of the water supply assets, these arrangements do not necessarily mean permanence. Typically, the government only allows the right to supply water under an operating license. This license can include a clause that permits its revocation or a not to renew clause. Thus, certain experts claim that the difference between a traditional fixed term concession and indefinite divestiture with a license may not be as significant as it might first appear.

Footnote: Guislain, Pierre (1997), The Privatization Challenge: A Strategic, Legal and Institutional Analysis of International Experience Washington DC: The World Bank.




“Ownership” of Water Facilities in Armenia

In Armenia, domestic water supply and sewer services are supplied either by local municipalities or State owned stock companies. There are five State owned stock companies in Armenia, the State owns 100% of the shares in Armenian Water, Nor Akung and Yerevan. The State owns 51% of the stock in Lori and Shirak while the other 49% is owned by the local government (Marz or County).

Two private operators exist in Armenia: (1) “SAUR” SA Company (France) which operates pursuant to a management agreement with Armenian Water; and (2) Veolia dba as Yerevan Jur (Armenian Company) operates Yerevan through a lease of assets.

Interestingly, many commentators have noted that water facility ownership is in a state of confusion. Understandably so. When Armenia declared its independence from the Soviet Union some 15 years ago, ownership became a question as to all of the “commons” including large apartment buildings, collective farms, and water facilities.

Since little capacity existed then (and now) locally, the State initially took ownership of these “commons.” Eventually, the ownership of apartment buildings and collective farms was divided by a combination of “historical use” and a lottery. Unfortunately, this division failed to identify the ownership of any remaining “commons” such as the water and sewer pipes in the apartment buildings. This same confusion carried forth to local water delivery and sewer systems where local governments were either non-existent or without sufficient capacity to manage and operate these facilities.

Solutions are not easy. After 15 years the State is invested in maintaining its “ownership.” The State cites its need to retain control because local governments continue to lack capacity, particularly in the ability to finance any large scale improvements, repairs, and even in some cases, the day to day operations and maintenance. The State’s argument is compelling.

One report issued in conjunction with the State suggests that moving toward privatization of all water facilities is the answer to the financing issue. However, such privatization in this case means to turn over the ownership of Armenian water facilities to French companies. It is also requires that ALL water services will be delivered via private companies. While there is no doubt that the French companies have capacity to manage these water systems, there are many public concerns particularly as to consumer cost.

The State’s report in support of its privatization conclusion makes an all or nothing conclusion: In order to provide efficient and cost effective water services to all Armenia, private companies should provide water throughout Armenia, both in urban and rural areas. While the report recognizes that individuals can be self supplied by wells, it fails to mention or address the effectiveness of self-regulated and owned small community water associations.

Likely the State’s argument against incorporating individual supply and small community water associations in the Armenian mix of water delivery services, is again “capacity.” In general, this means that the population of Armenia maintain a “Russian” mentality preferring to allow the State to take the responsibility. However, given the very certain realities of the escalating costs to consumers under privatization, Armenians may well be interested in alternatives. Preserving flexibility as Armenian sorts out the ownership of the “commons” relative to water delivery and sewer facilities will be challenging.




Many Newland Farmers See End in Sight

Personal service means just what it says! On March 28, 2008, in United States v. Alpine Land and Reservoir Co., Judge Lloyd D. George reaffirmed that only those 281 individual water right holders who returned their acknowledgement of service must defend the Pyramid Lake Paiute Tribe’s suit challenging the existence of their water rights. The Court’s recent order went on to confirm that those 1300 water right holders who had determined not to mail back an acknowledgment of the Tribe’s mailed service are dismissed.

Importantly, Judge George recognized our continued attempts in the last decade to dismiss the suit for lack of prosecution. Because of those efforts made by Schroeder Law Offices, PC on behalf of its clients, the Court determined that purchasers of lands with challenged water rights who had been served, ie mailed in the acknowledgements, are not bound by the currently filed petition. So the best news might be that of the 281 acknowledged individuals, those that sold the property along with the challenged water rights can also be dismissed.

Unless the Tribe refiles its petition against those dismissed, the number of individuals with challenges to the existence of their water rights is becoming quite small. Good news for Newlands Farmers! The end IS in sight!




Current Armenian Water Issues

Like most former soviet countries, Armenia continues to confront law and regulation of its natural resources from the top down. USAID through PA Consulting requested my consulting assistance approximately 16 months ago to assist it in redrafting and de-centralizing the approach to water management. I am currently on my fourth “mission.”

Many important laws and regulations have met agency approval some months ago. However, there are a few issues including dam inspection and safety which are yet unresolved. Perhaps it is simply a matter of communication between the agencies and, as usual, they are wrangling over the extent of each agency’s authority.

It is my opinion, and that of others, that Armenia quite desperately needs an overhaul of its water code as it pertains to its hydro technical structures because the present code provides no protection for any citizen against failure. Hopefully, a new code will provide security to the people of Armenia through routine dam inspections, maintenance, and clear statements of owners’ rights and responsibilities.




Northwest Connection to International Water

Our work in Armenia involves reviewing contracts between the State and a couple of the largest water purveying companies in the world, Veolia and Suez, which are headquartered in France.

Interestingly, we have found that these French companies, through their subsidiaries Veolia Water North America and United Water, also have contracts in Oregon, Washington, and Idaho. Examples include Operation and Maintenance contracts between Veolia and the cities of Wilsonville, OR and Vancouver, WA, and contracts between United Water and Boise, ID.

Links to these companies can be found at www.veoliawaterna.com and www.unitedwater.com.




Water Rights Bootcamp in Baker City, Oregon

Yesterday, I had the privilege of teaching a Water Law Bootcamp for Water for Life. Over forty people attended at the Baker County Fairgrounds in Baker City Oregon. Unlike previous presentations, attendees focused their questions primarily on due diligence water rights review in real estate transactions and valuations of water rights when lending on water righted properties. Apparently in these economic times, realtors and lenders are giving much more scrutiny to what water rights exist on the property subject to a transaction.




Political Unrest Complicates Armenian Water Delivery

Armenia’s Presidential election unrest may delay our next mission to assist the government in a review and updating of contracts between the State and the French contractors now purveying water to Yerevan and a few other cities in Armenia.

In preparing for this work, Katherine Thomas has found many cities in the West that also contract with American subsidiaries of these same French contractors. The world is small–or the French contractors are big!